p19 ... around 1980 things began to change with the emergence of fundamentalist
free-market governments in Britain and the US and the later disintegration of the state-run command economy in the former
Soviet Union. The formula for economic progress adopted by the administrations of Margaret Thatcher in the UK and Ronald Reagan
in the US called for a drastic reduction in the regulatory role of the state. Instead, government was to take a back seat
to corporate executives and money managers. The overall philosophy was that companies must be free to move their operations
anywhere in the world to minimize costs and maximize returns to investors. Free trade, unfettered investment, deregulation,
balanced budgets, low inflation and privatization of publicly-owned enterprises were trumpeted as the six-step plan to national
prosperity. Hand-in-hand with the spread of free trade in goods and services came the deregulation of world financial markets.
Banks, insurance companies and investment dealers which had been confined within national borders were suddenly unleashed.
Within a few years the big players from Europe, Japan and North America expanded into each other's markets as well as into
the newly-opened and fragile financial services markets in the South. Aided by computer technology and welcoming governments,
the big banks and investment houses were keen to invest surplus cash in anything that would turn a quick profit. In this new
relaxed atmosphere finance capital became a profoundly destabilizing influence on the global economy. Instead of long-term
investment in the production of real goods and services, speculators make money from money, with little concern for the impact
of their investments on local communities or national economies. Governments everywhere now fear the destabilizing impact
of this global financial casino. Recent United Nations (UN) studies show a direct correlation between the frequency of financial
crises and the increase in international capital flows during the l990s.
p24 The Bretton
Woods Trio As World War II was drawing to a close, the world's leading politicians and government officials, mostly from the
victorious 'Allied' nations (Britain, Canada, Australia, New Zealand and the United States) began to think about the need
to establish a system of rules to run the postwar global economy. Before the widespread outbreak of the war in 1939 trading
nations everywhere had been racked by a crippling economic depression. When the US stock market crashed in 1929 nations turned
inward in an attempt to pull themselves out of the steep skid. But without a system of global rules there was no coherence
or larger logic to the 'beggar-thy-neighbor' polices adopted worldwide. High tariff barriers were thrown up between countries
with the result that world trade nose-dived, economic growth spluttered and mass unemployment and poverty followed. As a result
the 1930s became a decade of radical politics and rancorous social ferment in the West as criticism of laissez-faire capitalism
and an unchecked market economy grew. Scholars like Karl Polanyi helped to reinforce a growing suspicion of a market-based
economic model which put money and investors at the center of its concerns rather than social values and human well-being.
'To allow the market mechanism to be the sole director of the fate of human beings and their natural environment... would
result in the demolition of society,' Polanyi wrote in his masterwork, The Great Transformation.
Polanyi was not alone in his distrust of the market economy. Other thinkers
like the influential Cambridge-educated economist John Maynard Keynes were also grappling with a way of controlling global
markets, making them work for people and not the other way around. Keynes both admired and feared the power of the market
system. With the memory of the Great Depression of the 1930s still fresh in his mind he predicted that, without firm boundaries
and controls, capitalism would be immobilized by its own greed, and would eventually self-destruct. As it happened only World
War Two turned things around. The War set the factories and farms humming again as millions of troops were deployed by all
sides in the conflict. Armaments manufacturers, aircraft factories and other military suppliers ran 24-hour shifts. Years
later, as the war wound down, government policy makers began to think about how to ensure a smooth transformation to a peacetime
economy. It was Keynes' radical notion of an 'interventionist' state to which governments turned in an effort to set their
economies back on a steady keel. Until the worldwide slump of the 1930s the accepted economic wisdom had been that unemployment
was a 'normal condition' of the free market. The economy might go up and down according to the normal business cycle but in
the long run, growth (and increased global trade) would create new jobs and sop up the unemployed. Keynes was skeptical of
this orthodoxy, suggesting that the economy was a human-made artifact and that people acting together through their government
could have some control over its direction. Why not act now, he suggested, since 'in the long run we're all dead. His approach
offered a way out for governments who found themselves helplessly mired in economic stagnation. In The General Theory of Employment,
Interest and Money published in 1936, Keynes argued that the free market, left on its own, actually creates unemployment.
Profitability, he said, depends on suppressing wages and cutting costs by replacing labor with technology. In other words
profits and a certain amount of unemployment go hand-in-hand. So far so good, at least for those making the profits. But then
Keynes showed that lowering wages and laying off workers would inevitably result in fewer people who could afford to buy the
goods that factories were producing. As demand fell, so would sales, and factory owners would be forced to lay off even more
workers. This, reasoned Keynes, was the start of a downward spiral with terrible human consequences. To 'prime the economic
pump' Keynes suggested governments intervene actively in the economy. He reasoned that business owners and rich investors
are unlikely to open their wallets if the prospects for growth look dim. When the economy is in a tailspin then it is up to
government to step in - by spending on public goods like education, health care, job training, roads, dams, trams and railways.
And by wading in with direct financial support to the unemployed. Even if governments had to go into debt to kickstart economic
growth Keynes advised politicians not to worry. The price was worth it. By directly stimulating the economy, government could
rekindle demand and help reverse the downward spiral. Soon companies would begin to invest again to increase production to
meet the growing demand. This would mean hiring more workers with more money in their pockets. As jobs increased so would
taxes. Eventually, the government would be able to pay back its debt from increased tax revenues raised from a now healthy,
growing economy. Desperate Western governments were quick to adopt the 'Keynesian' solution to economic stagnation. In the
US the 'New Deal' policies of the Roosevelt administration were directly influenced by Keynes. The American Employment Act
of 1946 accepted the federal government's responsibility 'to promote maximum employment, production and purchasing power'.
The British Government, too, in 1944 accepted as one of its primary aims 'the maintenance of a high and stable level of employment
after the war.' Other countries like Canada, Australia and Sweden quickly followed. Keynes' influence spread and people began
to believe that economics was finally a manageable science in the service of human progress. p27 Bretton Woods The aim of the Bretton Woods Conference [July 1944 ] was to erect a new framework
for the postwar global economy - a stable, cooperative international monetary system which would promote national sovereignty
and prevent future financial crises. The purpose was not to bury capitalism but to save it. The main proposal was for a system
of fixed exchange rates. In the light of the depression of the previous decade floating rates were now seen as inherently
unstable and destructive of national development plans. Keynes' influence at Bretton Woods was significant. But despite his
lobbying and cajoling he did not win the day on every issue. In the end the huge military and economic clout of the Americans
proved impossible to overcome. The Conference rejected his proposals to establish a world 'reserve currency' administered
by a global central bank. Keynes believed this would have created a more stable and fairer world economy by automatically
recycling trade surpluses to finance trade deficits. However his solution did not fit the interests of the United States,
eager to take on the role of the world's economic powerhouse. Instead the Conference opted for a system based on the free
movement of goods with the American dollar as the international currency. The dollar was linked to gold and the price of gold
was fixed at $35 an ounce (28g). In effect the US dollar became 'as-good-as-gold' and in this one act became the dominant
currency of international exchange. Three governing institutions emerged from the gathering to oversee and coordinate the
global economy. These were not neutral economic mechanisms: they contained a powerful bias in favor of global competition
and corporate enterprise. And each had a distinct role to play: INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND (IMF) The IMF was born with a
mission: to create economic stability for a world which had just been through the trauma of depression and the devastation
of war. As originally conceived it was supposed to 'facilitate the expansion and balanced growth of international trade' and
'to contribute to the promotion and maintenance of high levels of employment and real income'. A major part of its job was
to oversee a system of 'fixed' exchange rates. This was supposed to stop countries from devaluing their national currencies
to get a competitive edge over their neighbors - a defining feature of the economic chaos of the 1930s. Another part of the
Fund's mandate was to promote currency 'convertibility' - to make it easier to exchange one currency for another when trading
across national borders and in this way to encourage world trade. And finally the new agency was to act as a 'lender-of-last-resort'
supplying emergency loans to countries which ran into short-term cash flow problems. Keynes' idea was to set up an International
Clearing Union which would automatically provide unconditional loans to countries experiencing balance-of-payments problems.
These loans would be issued 'no strings attached' and their purpose would be to support domestic demand and maintain employment.
Otherwise countries feeling the pinch would be forced to balance their deficit by cutting off imports and smothering their
domestic economy. Keynes argued that international trade was a two-way street and that the 'winners' (those countries in surplus)
were as obligated as the 'losers' (those countries in deficit) to bring the system back into balance. In fact, Keynes suggested
that pressure be brought to bear on surplus nations so they would be forced to increase their imports and recycle the surplus
to deficit nations. But Keynes' view did not prevail. Instead a proposal put forward by US Treasury Secretary Harry Dexter
White became the basis for the IMF. The International Clearing Union idea disappeared. IMF members would not automatically
receive loans when they tumbled into deficit. Instead members would have access to limited loan amounts which were to be determined
by a complex quota system. When a country joins the IMF it is assigned a quota which is calculated in Special Drawing Rights
(SDRs), the Fund's own unit of account. Quotas are assigned according to a country's relative position in the world economy
which means that the most powerful economies have the most influence and clout. The US for example has the largest SDR quota
at about 27 billion. The size of a member's quota determines a lot, including how many votes it has in IMF deliberations and
how much foreign exchange it has access to if it runs into choppy financial waters. Balance-of-payments loans are at less
than the prevailing rate and members are supposed to use and repay them within five years. The issue of whether the IMF could
attach conditions to these loans was lost in the verbiage of the original Bretton Woods agreement. But Harry Dexter White
was very clear six months later when he wrote in the journal Foreign Affairs that the Fund would not simply dole out money
to debtor countries. The IMF would force countries to take measures which under the old gold standard (see p34) would have
happened automatically. While the framers of the Bretton Woods agreements supported a gradual reduction of trade barriers
and tariffs they were less enthusiastic about allowing the free movement of capital internationally. Keynes, Britain's delegate
to the meeting, advocated a balanced world trade system with strict controls on the movement of capital across borders. He
held that the free movement of all goods and capital, advocated most powerfully by the US delegation, would inevitably lead
to inequalities and instabilities. WORLD BANK (INTERNATIONAL BANK FOR RECONSTRUCTION AND DEVELOPMENT) One of the other key
goals of the Bretton Woods Conference was to find a way to rebuild the economies of those nations that had been devastated
by World War Two. The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (IBRD) was created to spearhead this effort. The
Bank is funded by dues from its members and by money borrowed on international capital markets. It makes loans to members
below rates available at commercial banks. Its initial mandate was to provide loans for economic 'infrastructure' which included
things like power plants, dams, roads, airports, ports, agricultural development and education systems. The Bank poured money
into reconstruction and development in Europe after World War Two. But it was not enough and it was not fast enough to satisfy
the United States whose booming industries were in need of viable markets. In response the US set up its own, much looser,
Marshall Plan which directly provided dollars to European nations, largely in the form of grants rather than loans. As Europe
gradually recovered in the 1950s the IBRD turned its interest to the newly-independent countries of the Third World where
it became widely known as the World Bank. As Southern countries sought to enter the industrial age the Bank became a major
player throughout the region. According to the 'stages of growth' economic theory popular at the time, developing nations
could achieve economic 'take-off' only from a strong infrastructure 'runway'. It was part of the Bank's self-defined role
to build this 'infrastructural capacity' and this it did enthusiastically by funding hydroelectric projects and highway systems
throughout Latin America, Asia and Africa But despite the Bank's concessional lending rates it was clear early on that the
very poorest countries would have difficulty meeting loan repayments. So in the late 1950s the Bank was pressured into setting
up the International Development Association (IDA). This wing of the Bank was to provide 'soft loans' with very low interest
or none at all - and so head off attempts by the new countries of the Third World to set up an independent funding agency
separate from the Bretton Woods institutions which could operate under UN auspices. The Bank also established two other departments:
the International Finance Corporation which supports private-sector investment in Bank-approved projects, and the Multilateral
Insurance Guarantee Agency, which provides risk insurance to foreign corporations and individuals who decide to invest in
one of the Bank's member countries. GENERAL AGREEMENT ON TARIFFS AND TRADE (GATT)/WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION (WTO) The GATT
established a set of rules to govern global trade. Its aim was to reduce national trade barriers and to stop the competitive
trade policies that had so hobbled the global economy prior to World War Two. Seven rounds of tariff reductions were negotiated
under the GATT treaty - the final 'Uruguay Round' began in 1986. March 1994, following completion of the final round of talks,
politicians and bureaucrats gathered in Marrakech, Morocco, to approve a new World Trade Organization (WTO) which was to replace
the more loosely-structured GATT. The WTO, unlike the GATT, has the official status of an international organization rather
than a loosely-structured treaty. It has 137 member states and 30 'observers' and vastly expands GATT's mandate in new directions.
The text of the WTO agreement had 26,000 pages: its sheer physical size is a hint of both its prolixity and its complexity.
It includes the GATT agreements which mostly focus on trade in goods. But it also folds in the new General Agreement on Trade
in Services (GATS) which potentially affects more than 160 areas including telecommunications, banking and investment, transport,
education, health and the environment. From the outset GATT was seen as a 'rich man's club' dominated by Western industrial
nations which were slow to concede their position of power. The WTO continues this tradition of rich world domination. p33 The WTO pursues its free trade agenda with the single-minded concentration
of the true believer. Nonetheless there is a growing unease about the organization's globalizing agenda. Critics are especially
wary of the new Dispute Settlement Body (DSB) which gives the WTO the legal tools to approve tough trade sanctions by one
member against another, especially on nations which might disagree with the organization's interpretation of global trade
rules. Any member country, acting on behalf of a business with an axe to grind, can challenge the laws and regulations of
another country on the grounds that they violate WTO rules.
p36 All nations have the right to use the DSB to pursue their own economic
self-interest. But the fact is that the world's major trading nations are also its most powerful economic actors and so the
tendency is for the strong to use the new rules to dominate weaker countries. The 'national treatment clause' basically says
that a country may not discriminate against products of foreign origin on any grounds whatsoever. And in so doing it removes
the power of national governments to develop economic policy which serves the moral, ethical or economic interests of their
citizenry. For example, if goods are produced by children in sweatshop conditions that doesn't enter the equation. And the
same is true if a foreign factory fouls the air and poisons the water, if poverty wages are paid to the workers who produce
the stuff, or if the goods themselves are poisonous and dangerous. According to WTO rules any country that refuses to import
a product on the grounds that it may harm public health or damage the environment has to prove the case scientifically. So
Canada, the world's biggest asbestos producer, has petitioned the WTO's dispute panel to force the European Community to import
the known carcinogen once again. And when the European Union (EU) refused imports of hormone-fed beef from North America,
the US took the case to the WTO arguing that there was no threat to human health from cows fed hormones. The EU ban on hormone-fed
beef applied to their own farmers as well as foreign producers but that made little difference. The WTO panel decided in favor
of the US, effectively ruling that Europeans had no right to pass laws that supported their opposition to hormones. The EU
was ordered to compensate producers in the US and Canada for every year of lost export earnings. And in retaliation the US
imposed 100 per cent tariffs on a range of European imports including mustard, pork, truffles and Roquefort cheese. Meanwhile,
the giant US-based shipping company, United Parcel Service (UPS), has been lobbying Washington to take Canada's government-run
postal service to the WTO dispute panel. UPS says that Ottawa is unfairly subsidizing Canada Post and therefore poaching potential
customers. Ottawa in its turn has announced its intention to prohibit the export of fresh water from Canada by a California-based
company. And so it goes in the topsy-turvy new world of economic globalization. Those institutions which first emerged from
the Bretton Woods negotiations half a century ago have become more important players with each passing decade. It is their
vision and their agenda which continue to shape the direction of the global economy. Together, they are fostering a model
of liberalized trade and investment which is heartily endorsed by the world's biggest banks and corporations. A deregulated,
privatized, corporate-led free market is the answer to humanity's problems, they tell us. The proof, though, is not so easily
found.
p38 Debt and structural adjustment The world has changed so dramatically
in the last half century that it's hard to believe that only four decades ago the newly emerging colonies of Africa and Asia
were joining with their nominally independent brethren in Latin America to push for a 'new international economic order' (NIEO).
Throughout the 1960s and early 1970s an insistent demand for radical change burst forth from the two-thirds of the world's
people who lived outside the privileged circle of North America and Western Europe. There was a powerful movement to shake
off the legacy of colonialism and to fight for a new global system based on economic justice between nations. Some Third World
nations began to explore ways of increasing their bargaining power with the industrialized countries in Europe and North America
by taking advantage of their control over key resources. Groups like the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC)
hoped to cooperate together to control the supply of petroleum and ratchet up the price of oil, thereby increasing their share
of global wealth and bringing prosperity to their populations. There was heady talk of 'producer cartels' to raise the price
of exports like sugar, coffee, cocoa, tin and rubber. That way poor countries that were critically dependent on one or two
primary commodities could gain more income and more control over their own development. There was also strong and vocal opposition
to the growing power of transnational corporations who were seen to be remaking the world in their own interests. But when
poor countries did try to force up the price of their primary exports they often found themselves faced with near-monopoly
control by Western corporations of processing, distribution and marketing. When the declaration of principles for an NIEO
was issued in 1974 it was the culmination of a new 'solidarity of the oppressed' which had spread throughout the developing
nations. Galvanized by centuries-old colonial injustices and sparked by the radical ideas of Fanon in Algeria, Nkrumah in
Ghana, Gandhi in India, Sukarno in Indonesia, Nyerere in Tanzania and Castro m Latin America, these 'Third World' nations
set out to collectively challenge the entrenched power of the United States and Western Europe. The NIEO was not a grassroots
movement. It was a collection of progressive intellectuals and politicians who believed correctly that, left on their own,
free markets would never reduce global inequalities. Instead these leaders argued for improved 'terms of trade' and a more
just international economic system. When bargaining failed producer countries began to form trade alliances based on specific
commodities. Third World nations came together in political organizations like the Non-Aligned Movement which was initially
an attempt to break out of the polarized East/West power struggle between the West and the Soviet Bloc. In the United Nations,
developing countries formed the 'Group of 77' which was instrumental in creating the UN Conference on Trade and Development
(UNCTAD). Within UNCTAD poor countries pushed for fairer 'terms of trade'. Many newly-independent countries of the South still
relied heavily on the export of raw materials in the 1950s and 1960s. But there was a faltering effort and a stronger belief
in the need to build local industrial capacities and to support the push for a 'new international economic order'. Why was
it, they asked, that the price of everything they imported from the West, whether it was manufactured goods, spare parts or
foodstuffs, seemed to creep ever upwards while the prices they received for their agricultural exports and raw materials remained
the same - or even decreased? The transparent injustice of this enraged and frustrated leaders like Tanzania's Julius Nyerere
who referred to declining terms of trade as constantly 'riding the downward escalator'. Between 1980 and 1991 alone non-oil-exporting
developing countries lost nearly $290 billion due to decreasing prices for their primary commodity exports. In response to
this economic discrimination Third World nations also began agitating for an increase in 'untied aid from the West; for more
liberal terms on development loans; and for a quicker transfer of new manufacturing technologies from North to South. In addition
most developing countries favored an active government role in running the national economy. They quite rightly feared that
in a world of vast economic inequality they could easily be crushed between self-interested Western governments and their
muscular business partners. That was the chief reason that many Third world nations began to take tentative steps to regulate
foreign investment and to maintain at least minimal trade restrictions. Latin American nations were especially successful
at encouraging 'import substitution as a way of boosting local manufacturing, employment and income Countries like Brazil
and Argentina used a mix of taxation policy, tariffs and financial incentives to attract both foreign and domestic investment.
American and European auto companies set up factories to take advantage of import barriers. The development goal was to stimulate
industrialization in order to produce goods locally and to boost export earnings. This had the added benefit of reducing imports,
which both cut the need for scarce foreign exchange and kept domestic capital circulating inside the country. Unfortunately,
the era of import substitution was short. Latin American nations were soon bullied into dismantling import barriers so that
by the late 1960s there were no local producers of cars, TVs, iceboxes/fridges or other major household goods. Still, this
was a brief but important step in trying to shift the balance of global power to poor countries. New economic order But even
before the clamor for a new world economic order, momentous changes were beginning to unfold that would dramatically alter
the fate of poor nations for decades to come. By the late 1960s the Bretton Woods dream of a stable monetary system of fixed
exchange rates with the dollar as the only international currency was collapsing under the strain of American trade and budgetary
deficits. The United States' economy was firing on all cylinders and beginning to dangerously overheat. As the war in Vietnam
escalated, the Federal Reserve in Washington pumped out millions of dollars to finance the conflict. Inflation edged upwards
and the US foreign debt ballooned to pay for the war. World Bank President Robert McNamara also leapt into the fray and contracted
huge loans to the South during the 1970s - both for 'development' (essentially defined as basic infrastructure to bring 'backward'
economies into the market system) and to act as a bulwark against a perceived worldwide communist threat. The Bank's stake
in the South increased five-fold over the decade. At the same time a guarded optimism took hold in the South, fueled by moderately-high
growth rates and a short-term boom in the price of primary commodities particularly oil. The Organization of Petroleum Exporting
Countries (OPEC) was the first, and ultimately the most successful, Third World 'producer union'. By standing together and
controlling the supply of oil they were able to increase the price of petroleum three-fold to over $30 a barrel. The result
was windfall surpluses for OPEC members - $310 billion for the period 1972-1977 alone. This 'oil shock' rippled through the
global economy, triggering double-digit inflation and a massive 'recycling' problem. What were OPEC nations to do with this
vast new wealth of 'petrodollars'? Some of it they would spend on glittering new airports, power stations and other showcase
mega-projects. But much of it eventually wound up as investment in Northern financial centers or deposited in Northern commercial
banks. This was the birth of the 'eurocurrency' market - a huge pool of cash held outside the borders of the countries that
originally issued the currency. The US dollar was the main 'eurocurrency' but there were also francs, guilders, marks and
pounds. Western banks, flush with this new OPEC money, then began to search for borrowers. They didn't have long to look.
Soon millions in loans were contracted to non-oil-producing Third World governments desperate to pay escalating fuel bills
and to fund ambitious development goals. At the same time the massive increase in oil prices helped inflation soar around
the world. Prices skyrocketed while growth slowed to a crawl and a new word was added to the lexicon of economists: 'stagflation'.
In the midst of this economic chaos US President Richard Nixon moved unilaterally to de-link the dollar from gold. As a result
the world moved to a system of floating exchange rates. Nixon also devalued the greenback (US dollar) against other major
world currencies and jacked up interest rates, a move which had an enormous impact on the global economy. By slashing the
value of the dollar Washington effectively reduced the huge debt it owed to the rest of the world. The US had been running
a large deficit in order to pay the costs of the war in Vietnam. As interest rates shot up, those countries reeling under
OPEC oil-price hikes had the cost of their eurodollar loans (most of which were denominated in US dollars) double and even
triple, almost overnight. The debt of the non-oil producing Third World increased five-fold between 1973 and 1982, reaching
a staggering $612 billion. The banks were desperate to lend to meet their interest obligations on deposits so easy terms were
the order of the day. Dictators who could exact payments from their cowering populations with relative ease must have seemed
like a good bet for lenders looking for a secure return. Sometimes the petrodollar loan money was squandered on grandiose
and ill-considered projects. Sometimes it was simply filched - siphoned off by Third World elites into personal accounts in
the same Northern banks that had made the original loans. Often it was both wasted and stolen. Foolish loans The experience
was similar across the South. From the mid-1960s to the mid-1980s, despotism pervaded Latin America and employed an ingenious
variety of scams wherever it went. In Asia and Africa, megalomaniacs with powerful friends and large appetites for personal
wealth were financed with enthusiasm by the international banking fraternity. Indeed, it seemed to work so well that the credit
lines became almost limitless - particularly if the governments in question were fighting on the right side of the Cold War
and buying large quantities of armaments from Northern suppliers. Examples of these foolish loans to corrupt leaders are well
known. In the Philippines, dictator Ferdinand Marcos along with his wife Imelda and their cronies are estimated to have pocketed
in the form of kickbacks and commissions a third of all loans to that country. Before he was forced out of office, Marcos'
personal wealth was estimated at $10 billion. Meanwhile, there are no records for 80 per cent of the $40 billion borrowed
by the Argentinean military dictatorship from 1976 to 1983. Argentineans are demanding that their Government either produce
accounts or have the debts declared illegal. It seems that New York banks knew money was being misused, that there had been
kickbacks and fraudulent loans to companies linked to the military, and that the IMF allegedly connived with the fraud. It
is also clear that the military used some of the loans to buy weapons for the Falklands/Malvinas War. Deeper in debt From
1997 to the first year of the millennium, the 'Jubilee 2000' citizens' movement led a worldwide campaign to cancel the debts
of the world's poorest countries. Jubilee researchers found that almost a quarter of all Third World debt (nearly $500 billion)
is the result of loans used to prop up dictators in some 25 different countries. ~ The money flowed free and fast through
the 1980s and early 1990s. But eventually the soaring tower of debt began to creak and sway. One government after the next
began to run into financial trouble. The loans they had raised and squandered on daft projects or salted away in private bank
accounts became so large their foreign exchange earnings and tax revenues couldn't keep up the payments. During this period
the IMF became an enforcer of tough policy conditions on poor countries that were forced to apply to the Fund for temporary
balance-of-payments assistance. During the 1970s and early 1980s the IMF's loans were conditional on governments following
the advice of the Fund's economists who had their own take on what Southern nations were doing wrong and how they could fix
it. The Fund's demands were woven into the deals worked out with those countries that required an immediate transfusion of
cash. Essentially, the agency argued that the debtor country's problems were caused by 'excessive demand' in the domestic
economy. Curiously, the responsibility of the private banks who made most of the dubious loans in the first place (with their
eyes wide open it should be noted) was ignored. The IMF prescription According to the Fund this excessive demand meant there
were too many imports and not enough exports. The solution was to devalue the currency and cut government spending. This was
supposed to slow the economy and reduce domestic demand, gradually resulting in fewer imports, along with more, and cheaper,
exports. In time, the IMF argued, the balance-of-payments deficit would be eliminated. Countries were more or less forced
to adopt these austerity measures if they wanted to get the IMF 'seal of approval'. Without it they would be ostracized on
the fringes of the global economy. Both the IMF and the World Bank also urged debtor nations to take on deeper 'structural
adjustment' measures as early as the 1970s but borrowing countries refused to go along with the advice. Then in 1982 Mexico
told its creditors it could no longer pay and a full-fledged Third World 'debt crisis' emerged. Northern politicians and bankers
began to worry that the sheer volume of unpayable loans would undermine the world financial system. Widespread panic began
to sweep through the world of international finance as scores of Southern nations teetered on the brink of economic collapse.
In response both the Bank and the IMF hardened their line and began to demand major changes in the way debtor nations ran
their domestic economies. Countries like Ghana were forced to toe the line and enforce tough adjustment conditions as early
as 1983. A few years later, the US Treasury Secretary James Baker decided to formalize this new strategy to force Third World
economies to radically 'restructure' their economies to meet their debt obligations. The 'Baker Plan' was introduced at the
1985 meeting of the World Bank and the IMF when both agencies were called on to impose more thorough 'adjustments' to the
economic policies of debtor countries. The Bank and the Fund made full use of this new leverage. Together they launched a
policy to 'structurally adjust' the Third World by deflating economies and demanding a withdrawal of government - not only
from public enterprise but also from compassionate support of the basic health and welfare of the most vulnerable. Exports
to earn foreign exchange were privileged over basic necessities, food production and other goods for domestic use. Y The Fund
set up its first 'formal' Structural Adjustment Facility in 1986. The World Bank soon followed, so that by 1989 the Bank had
contracted adjustment loans to 75 per cent of the countries that already had similar IMF loans in place. The Bank's conditions
both extended and reinforced the IMF prescription for financial 'liberalization' and open markets. They included 'privatizing'
state-owned enterprises; reducing the size and cost of government through massive public sector layoffs; cutting basic social
services and subsidies on basic foodstuffs; and reducing barriers to trade. This restructuring was highly successful from
the point of view of the private banks who siphoned off more than $178 billion from the South between 1984 and 1990 alone.
Structural adjustment programs (SAPs) were in fact an extremely effective mechanism for transforming private debt into public
debt. The 1980s were a 'lost decade' for much of the Third World. Growth stagnated and debt doubled to almost $1,500 billion
by the decade's end. By 1999 it had reached nearly $3,000 billion. An ever-increasing proportion of this new debt was to service
interest payments on the old debt, to keep money circulating and to keep the system up-and-running. Most of this debt had
shifted from private banks to the IMF and the World Bank - though the majority was still owed to rich countries and Northern
banks. The big difference was that the Fund and the Bank were always first in line so paying them was a much more onerous
prospect. Taking more out The stark fact that the Fund and the Bank began operating with reverse capital flows (in other words
they were then taking more money out of the Third World than they were putting back in) was sobering for those who believed
those institutions were there to help. In six of the eight years from 1990 to 1997 developing countries paid out more in debt
service (interest plus repayments) than they received in new loans: a total transfer from South to North of $77 billion. And
most of the increase was used to meet interest payments rather than for productive investment. After 1998 the balance changed
again as a result of massive bailout packages to Mexico and Asia. However, this will likely set the stage for negative flows
again in the near future. The 'conditionalities' of structural adjustment meanwhile diverted government revenues away from
things like education and healthcare, towards debt repayment and the promotion of exports. This gave the World Bank and IMF
a degree of control that even the most despotic of colonial regimes rarely achieved. Even former enthusiastic supporters of
structural adjustment were forced to reconsider their faith in this 'neo-liberal' recipe for economic progress. In 1999, Harvard
University's 'economic shock-therapy' advocate Jeffrey Sachs wrote: 'Many of the three billion of the world's poorest live
in countries whose governments have long since gone bankrupt under the weight of past credits from foreign governments, banks
and agencies such as the World Bank and the IMF. These countries have become desperate wards of the IMF... Their debts should
be canceled outright and the IMF sent home. The situation has remained essentially unchanged ever since. In nations as far
apart as Yugoslavia, Rwanda and Peru, the privations suffered in the name of debt repayments lay concealed behind outbreaks
of violent civil unrest. All attempts to organize relief for the South were rebuffed on principle until 1996, when the 'Heavily
Indebted Poor Countries Initiative' was launched to make debt repayments 'sustainable'. Within a decade, the 'cold' war which
ended in 1989 was replaced by a 'financial' war that is still being fought. Two decades of structural adjustment has not only
failed to solve the debt crisis, it has caused untold suffering for millions and led to widening gaps between rich and poor.
A 1999 study by the Washington-based group, Development Gap, looked at the impact of SAPs on more than 70 African and Asian
countries during the early 1990s. The study concluded that the longer a country operates under structural adjustment the worse
its debt burden becomes. SAPs, Development Gap warned, 'are likely to push countries into a tragic circle of debt, adjustment,
a weakened domestic economy, heightened vulnerability and greater debt.' 6 Debt's legacy So we are left with a bizarre and
degrading spectacle. In Africa, external debt has ballooned by 400 per cent since the Bank and the IMF began managing national
economies through structural adjustment. Today in Ethiopia a hundred thousand children die annually from easily preventable
diseases, while debt repayments are four times more than public spending on healthcare. In Tanzania, where 40 per cent of
people die before the age of 35, debt payments are 6 times greater than spending on healthcare. From the whole of Africa,
where one in every two children of primary-school age is not in school, governments transfer four times more to Northern creditors
in debt payments than they spend on the health and education of their citizens. Structural-adjustment programs may not have
put Third World countries back on a steady economic keel but they have certainly helped undermine democracy in those nations.
Joseph Stiglitz, former World Bank Chief Economist, is candid about the record of bureaucrats in both agencies undermining
the ability of nominally independent nation states to govern their own affairs. In an article written shortly after his resignation
Stiglitz said there are 'real risks associated with delegating excessive power to international agencies... The institution
can actually become an interest group itself, concerned with maintaining its position and advancing its power.' If we believe
in democratic processes he continues, 'countries must make the decisions for themselves, and the responsibility of economic
advisors is only to appraise them of prevailing views. The debt load on all governments, but particularly those of the Third
World, has crippled their capacity to look after their citizens. Capital moves so freely that it is often impossible for governments
to find, let alone tax. With the disintegration of the Soviet Union, the impoverishment of Africa and the resurgence of an
unfettered market system in Asia and Latin America the triumph of capitalism seems complete. Indeed, SAPs really only make
sense when seen through the lens of economic globalization. They are an integral part of the free-market orthodoxy which aims
to give free rein to private corporations to trade, invest and move capital around the globe with a minimum amount of government
interference. But there are cracks emerging in this seemingly uniform consensus. People in the South are resisting structural
adjustment through violent opposition and grassroots organizing. Protest too is coming from the millions uprooted by World
Bank mega-projects, particularly the building of massive hydroelectric dams. Rejection of all things Western is on the rise.
Fundamentalism and the politics of ethnic exclusion (from Somalia to Kosovo to India) are turning political costs into military
ones. And, as the Seattle protests of December 1999 illustrated, powerful and unaccountable institutions like the World Trade
Organization are coming under direct pressure from citizens' groups, community activists, students, trade unionists and environmentalists.
Many are calling for reform. Others are going much farther and demanding the outright abolition of these agencies and a complete
restructuring of &e global financial architecture.
p63 One of the corporate sector's greatest political victories in recent
decades has been to beat down corporate taxes. In Britain, the corporate tax rate fell from 52 per cent in 1979 to 30 per
cent in 2000 and Labor Prime Minister Tony Blair has boasted that British business is subject to even fewer strictures than
corporations in the US. Corporate tax rates have declined in virtually every OECD country over the last two decades as governments
rely more and more on personal income taxes and sales taxes for revenues. In 1950 corporate taxes in the US accounted for
30 per cent of government funds; today they account for less ~ than 12 per cent. Their sheer size, wealth and power means
that multinationals and the business sector in general have been able to structure the public debate on social issues and
the role of government in a way which benefits their own interests. They have used their louder voices and political clout
to build an effective propaganda machine and to boost what the great Italian political theorist Antonio Gramsci called their
'cultural hegemony'. Through sophisticated public relations, media manipulation and friends-in-high-places the neo-liberal
economic perspective has come to be accepted as the 'common sense' approach to running a country. This radical paradigm shift
has occurred in the short space of 30 years. A corporation's ultimate responsibility is to its shareholders, as Chief Executive
Officers (CEOs) constantly reassure their investors at annual general meetings. It is enhanced value for shareholders which
drives and structures corporate decision-making - without regard for the social, environmental and economic consequences of
those decisions. Unless obligations to the public good are imposed on companies the business agenda will continue to ride
roughshod over national and community interests. p65 Public disillusionment
with the WTO is now well known and opposition is growing to the organization's bottom-line brand of globalization. But if
activists hadn't stumbled across the MAI in 1997, efforts to inject human values into the debate on the global trading system
could have been severely curtailed. After the WTO came into being in 1994, the globe's major corporations began to put together
a plan for codifying the rules of world trade in a way that would give them complete freedom. They found it in the MAI, an
agreement which was drafted by the International Chamber of Commerce (a 'professional association' of the world's largest
companies) and presented to the rich-nation OECD members for discussion and, it was assumed, rubber-stamp approval. Once passed,
the next stop was to be the WTO. Third World governments were rightly suspicious of the MAI and many saw it as 'a throwback
to colonial era economics'. But, with the weight of the OECD behind it, supporters of the MAI reckoned it would be speedily
adopted as an official WTO document. Delegates from OECD countries began discussing the MAI in early 1995 behind closed doors.
By early 1997 most of the treaty was down on paper and the public was none the wiser. In fact, most politicians in the OECD's
29 member countries weren't even aware of the negotiations. It was only when activists in Canada got their hands on a copy
of the MAI and began sending it around the world via the Internet that the full scope of the document became clear. The MAI
was a corporate dream come true. Essentially the agreement set out to give private companies the same legal status as nation-states
in all countries that were party to the Agreement. But more importantly it set out a clear set of rules so that corporations
would be able to defend their new rights against the objections of sovereign governments. The MAI was so overwhelmingly biased
towards the interests of multinationals that critics were quick to label it 'the corporate rule treaty'. For example, under
MAI provisions corporations could sue governments for passing laws that might reduce their potential profits. They could make
their case in secret with no outside interest groups involved and the decision would be binding. The MAI also allowed foreign
investors to challenge public funding of social programs as a distortion of free markets and the 'level playing field'. If
a government chose to privatize a state-owned industry it could no longer give preference to domestic buyers. In addition,
governments would be forbidden to demand that foreign investment benefit local communities or the national economy. They could
not demand domestic content, local hiring, affirmative action, technology transfer or anything else in return for allowing
foreign companies to exploit publicly owned resources. And there were to be no limits on profit repatriation. Once the text
became public, citizens' groups around the world began vigorous education campaigns on the potentially-damaging impact of
the MAI. Two influential activists, Tony Clarke and Maude Barlow, summed up the feelings of citizens' groups everywhere. The
MAI, they wrote, 'would provide corporations with the right to directly enforce an international treaty to which they are
not party and under which they have no obligations. It would be entirely one-sided; neither citizens nor governments could
sue the corporations back. The MAI would provide foreign investors with new and substantive rights with which they could challenge
government programs, policies and laws all over the world. MAI protest In a few months public anxiety about the deal came
to a head. In France, Australia, Canada and the US politicians at all levels were drawn into the debate and governments were
forced to enter 'reservations' to protect themselves from certain of the MAI's provisions. By the May 1998 deadline it was
clear that the talks were at a standstill and that public opposition had torpedoed further progress on the Agreement. This
was a stunning victory for a growing international citizens' movement. But the end of the MAI as such did not spell the end
of the corporate agenda for an unregulated, global investment treaty. The focus would now shift to the WTO and other global
venues where multinationals could lobby for the MAI-like investment provisions.
p70 Fueled by a strong dollar and a vastly-overvalued stock market,
the American economy continues to suck in cheap imports from the rest of the world. The result is colossal domestic debt and
record trade deficits. In 1999 the US trade deficit soared to nearly $300 billion, almost triple the deficit of 1995.
p71 Over the past decade the UN has documented a\ steady shift of global
income from wages to profits throughout the world. Even so investors are no longer satisfied with five or six per cent annual
returns. As barriers to the free movement of capital started to crumble around the world, corporations, banks and other major
investors began to cast around anxiously for other surefire means of maximizing their returns. The solution was quick at hand.
From the 'real' economy of manufacturing and commodity production investors turned to the world of international finance.
Speculation and gambling in international money markets seemed an easier path than competing for fewer and fewer paying customers
in the old goods and services economy. The era of the 'global casino' had arrived.
p72 ... the biggest and most dangerous change over the past 30 years
has been in the area of global finance. The volume of worldwide foreign exchange transactions has exploded as country after
country has lowered barriers to foreign investment. In 1980 the daily average of foreign exchange trading totaled $80 billion;
today it is estimated that more than $1,500 billion changes hands daily on global currency markets. That is an unimaginable
sum of money, but it is all the more stunning when you realize that most of this investment has virtually nothing to do with
producing real goods and services for real people. In 1998 the annual global trade in merchandise and services was $6.5 billion
- equal to only 4.3 days of trading on foreign exchange markets. '
p72 Money chasing money has eclipsed productive investment as the motor
of the global economy. p73 Critics of corporate-led globalization
charge that \ unregulated flows of capital pose a major threat to the stability of the global economy, turning the world into
a 'global financial casino'. This free flow of capital has also had a direct political impact, leaving national governments
hostage to market sentiments. Any departure from the received wisdom is instantly , punished. This threat leads to a massive
degree of self-censorship and a serious loss of democracy.
p76 And crises we've seen ~ from 1973 to 1995 there were 11 major global
financial blow-ups. All of them required active intervention by international financial institutions and national governments
to keep the world system from collapsing. The last major one began in Southeast Asia in mid-1997 when 'hot money' panicked
and fled as quickly as it had arrived. Although the IMF and the US Government eventually stepped in with an emergency bailout
of more than $120 billion, the damage from the financial chaos was widespread. Currencies were devalued in Thailand Indonesia,
the Philippines and South Korea; factories were shut down, imports slashed, workers laid off and public sector services like
healthcare, education and transport cut drastically. As the UN Development Program commented in its 1999 Human Development
Report: 'The East Asian crisis in not an isolated accident, it is a symptom of general weakness in global capital markets.'
The UN agency was not alone in its assessment. Even the stridently pro-business magazine, The Economist, was forced to admit
that abrupt reversals in capital 'have challenged the conventional wisdom that it is a good thing to let capital move freely
across borders'. Others likeJagdish Bhagwati were less equivocal. He noted that 'the Asian crisis cannot be separated from
excessive borrowings of foreign short-term capital... It has become apparent that crises attendant on capital mobility cannot
be ignored.'
p77 The Southeast Asian economy went into freefall in the summer of
1997. p82 ... The set-back for development was so severe that non-governmental
agencies estimated it would take a decade or longer to make-up the lost ground. Oxfam analyzed the situation as follows: 'The
crisis now gripping East Asia bears comparison in terms of its destructive impact with the Great Depression of 1929. What
started as a financial crisis has been allowed to develop into a full-fledged social and economic crisis, with devastating
consequences for human development. Previously rising incomes have been reversed and unemployment and underemployment has
reached alarming levels. Rising food prices and falling social spending have further aggravated the social conditions of the
poorest.' The human impact of the crisis was stunning. According to the UN's International Labor Organization (ILO) more than
20 million people in Indonesia were laid off from September 1997 to September 1998. UNICEF said that 250,000 clinics in the
country were closed and predicted that infant mortality would jump by 30 per cent. The Asian Development Bank said that more
than six million children had dropped out of school. And Oxfam estimated that more than 100 million Indonesians were living
in poverty a year after the crisis -four times more than two years earlier. There was also a frightening resurgence of racial
'scape-goating' and inter-communal violence throughout the region. Malaysia's autocratic leader Mahathir Mohamad blamed Jewish
financiers for destabilizing his Muslim country, while in Indonesia the shops of ethnic-Chinese merchants were looted and
burned and hundreds of Chinese brutally beaten and killed. There were, however, some clear winners that emerged from the Asian
meltdown. The big ones were the Western corporate interests that rushed in to snap up the region's bargain-basement assets
after the economic collapse. As former US Trade Representative Mickey Kantor said at the time, the recession in the Tiger
Economies 'was a golden chance for the West to 'reassert' its commercial interests. 'When countries seek help from the IMF,'
he said, 'Europe and America should use the IMF as a battering ram to gain advantage.' That was certainly true in South Korea
where the IMF agreement lifted restrictions on outside ownership so that foreigners could purchase up to 55 per cent of Korean
companies and 100 per cent of Korean banks. Years of effort by the Korean elite to keep businesses firmly under control of
state-supported conglomerates called chaebols were undone in a matter of months. In January 1998 the French investment firm
Credit Lyonnais estimated that just 87 of the country's 653 non-financial firms were safe from foreign buyers. Rudi Dornbusch,
a US economist, accurately summed up the overall impact of the economic crisis. 'Korea is now owned and operated by our Treasury,'
he crowed. "That's the positive side of this crisis."
p89 The original Bretton Woods agreement did not fulfill Keynes' dream
of giving 'every member government the explicit right to control capital movements' but the policies did give members some
controls. Unfortunately, even these limited tools have been gradually eroded over the years by the growing insistence on deregulation.
US Treasury official Lawrence Summers criticized efforts by Malaysia, Hong Kong and others to hobble the movement of overseas
capital. He called controls a 'catastrophe' and urged countries to 'open up to foreign financial service providers, and all
the competition, capital and expertise they bring with them'. Given the damage inflicted on millions by the fickle nature
of short-term speculators, Summers' fundamentalism comes across as both short-sighted and harmful. As people from Mexico to
Russia see their lives wrecked by the whipsaw effect of one global financial crisis after another it is becoming painfully
evident that the old ways no longer work. The world has been led to the brink of financial chaos too often in the last decade.
Solutions are needed urgently to ensure that money markets, bond traders and currency speculators are brought under the control
of national governments in the interest of the public good.
p97 One of the most cogent critiques of the downside globalization came
from the UN Development Program in its 1999 Human Development Report. 'When the market goes too far in dominating social and
political outcomes, the opportunities and rewards of globalization spread unequally and inequitably - concentrating power
and wealth in a select group of people, nations and corporations, marginalizing the others.' The UN agency backed its analysis
with hard-hitting figures on what it called a 'grotesque and dangerous polarization' between those people and countries benefiting
from the system and those that are merely 'passive recipients' of its effects. Even on its own terms economic globalization
is not working. In 1960, the fifth of the world's people who live in the richest countries had 30 times more income than the
fifth living in the poorest countries. By 1997 the income gap had more than doubled to 74:1. Income inequalities within countries
have also increased over the past two decades. Another UN study, this one on income inequality in OECD countries, concluded
that in the 1980s real wages (adjusted for inflation) had fallen and income inequality increased in all countries except Germany
and Italy. The widening gap In the US the top ten per cent of families increased their average income by 16 per cent during
that decade, while the top five per cent increased theirs by 23 per cent and the top one per cent by a whopping 50 per cent.
This trend was echoed elsewhere. In Latin America the top 10 per cent of wage-earners increased their share of total income
by 10 per cent while the poorest 10 per cent saw their income drop by 15 per cent, wiping out what meager improvements they
had made in the previous decade. Income inequality also grew in Thailand, Indonesia, China and other Asian nations even though
the region enjoyed healthy economic growth throughout the decade. In sub-Saharan Africa the situation was worse: after two
decades of IMF and World Bank structural adjustment not only is income inequality growing but average per capita incomes are
falling. They are now lower than they were in 1970. This shift in wealth and income from bottom to top is part of the logic
of globalization. In order to be 'competitive' governments adopt policies which cut taxes and favor profits over wages. The
economic argument is simple: putting more money into the pockets of corporations and wealthy individuals (who benefit most
from tax cuts: the higher the income the greater the gain) will lead to greater investment, jobs, economic growth and good
times for all. Unfortunately, there is no evidence that improvements in public well-being result from tax cuts for the rich
or lower wages for the rest of us. If tax cuts were directed towards those at the bottom of the income ladder there might
be some impact since the money would almost certainly be spent on basic necessities. But this isn't part of the globalization
game plan. In every country that has taken up the 'reduce-taxes-cut-the-deficit' mantra the majority of tax cuts benefit wealthy
individuals and corporations. What happens to the money is perhaps predictable: some goes into high-priced consumer baubles
- a phenomenon which is glaringly visible amongst the elite in cities from Bangkok to Los Angeles. But most winds up in the
stock market or in other sorts of non-productive speculative activity.
p100 Despite ... worrying warning signs, neo-liberals are reluctant
to abandon their beliefs: 'Give the private sector the resources,' they say, 'and it will do the job.' But the proof is hard
to find. Surplus capital which doesn't get funneled into currency markets zips straight into overseas tax havens where both
rich individuals and globe-trotting multinationals have been squirreling away their cash for decades. There are nearly 70
tax havens scattered around the world. These 'offshore financial centers' include places like the Bahamas, the Cayman Islands,
Liberia and Bermuda. Investors can store their wealth secretly, no questions asked - thus escaping any social obligations
to the country where they may have earned it.
p102 As corporate profits boom and real wages stagnate, the glue that
holds us together is losing its strength. We're told there is no longer enough money to pay for 'public goods'. In exchange
for a few hundred dollars in tax cuts we sacrifice our schools, reduce state support for community parks and recreation facilities,
hobble our public transport and weaken our healthcare system In Western Europe, Canada, Australia and New Zealand (Aotearoa)
public education and healthcare systems have seen repeated budget cuts as the state retreats and makes way for private, profit-oriented
ventures. Welfare and unemployment benefits have been 'rationalized', slashing the number of those eligible. Senior citizens
and those nearing retirement are fearful that promised pensions will evaporate as governments become more desperate for funds.
Individuals are frantically scraping together whatever savings they have and heading towards the stock market in the hope
that they too will ride to old-age security on the coattails of the FTSE, the Nasdaq and the Dow Jones. Government funding
for the arts and for environmental protection has also been steadily eroded. This failure to protect these 'public goods'
diminishes us all, makes us less capable of caring for each other and prohibits us from advancing together as a cohesive,
mutually supportive community. Globalization has also derailed development in the South where the poor continue to pay the
highest price of adjustment. In order to boost exports and maintain their obligations to creditors, developing countries must
divert money away from things like healthcare, education and aid to small-scale farmers. There have been countless studies
detailing the social impact of structural adjustment and the findings are depressingly similar. Those with the least suffer
the most.
p104 The litany of suffering and chaos spawned by harsh l market reforms
is repeated across the developing world. A 1999 joint study by the Washington-based Development Gap and Friends of the Earth
confirmed this damage in five different poor countries. In Senegal, which has endured 20 years of IMF programs, the report
found 'declining quality in education and health' combined with a growth in 'maternal mortality, unemployment and child labor'.
In Tanzania the research found that globalization had successfully redirected agriculture towards exports but had also 'expanded
rural poverty, income inequality and environmental degradation'. Food security decreased housing conditions deteriorated and
primary-school enrollment dropped while malnutrition and infant mortality rose. In Mexico the report noted that globalization
led to 'economic depression'. Millions of farmers were pushed out of agriculture and thousands of small businesses went bankrupt
- 'drastically slashing jobs and wages' in the process. In Nicaragua, whose mildly leftist Sandinista government was destabilized
by the US in the 1980s, IMF policies drove the country into further poverty. Financial deregulation attracted capital to 'short-term,
high interest deposits' and 'away from productive investment in small-scale domestic agriculture and manufacturing'. In Hungary,
the IMF advised introducing liberalized trade, a tight money supply and rapid privatization of state assets. But the report
found the policies deflected money away from education and social services and into the wallets of wealthy bond holders. But
it was in Russia that the orthodox prescription for economic reform did some of its greatest harm. Supported by billions in
Western aid, subsidized loans and rescheduled debt, the plan was to turn Russia into a capitalist success story overnight.
Instead the 'shock therapy' threw the economy open to the winds of corruption. Privatized state assets ended up in the hands
of a small group of powerful insiders (often the same people who ran the former communist state apparatus) while ordinary
Russians were saddled with colossal debts. At the same time an estimated $150 billion left the country, most of it permanently.
Poverty in Russia In the absence of price controls and the guaranteed employment of the Soviet era, average Russians endured
poverty unknown for decades. It is estimated that 70 per cent of Russians now live below the poverty line while capital investment
is barely 10 per cent of what it was in 1990. The country has experienced the steepest fall in peacetime living standards
in modern history. According to the UN inequality doubled from 1989 to 1996. The income share of the richest 20 per cent of
Russians is 11 times that of the poorest 20 per cent. Much of the economy has returned to barter while male life expectancy
dropped from 65 to 60 years (two years less than the average for developing countries) and the under-five child mortality
rate jumped to 25 per thousand live births - the same as Libya or Venezuela
p111 The IMF does not exist in a vacuum. Governments fund it and in
return receive votes based on a 'one dollar, one vote' principle - in contrast to the UN's 'one country, one vote' system.
As a result, industrialized countries account for over 60 per cent of the voting strength at the IMF and World Bank, compared
with just 17 per cent in various UN bodies. The chief beneficiary is the U.S. which is the only country with a large-enough
slice of the votes to enjoy an effective veto of major IMF decisions. That, and the Fund's location in Washington, has helped
give the US disproportionate power in using the IMF to pursue its own international agenda.
p119 In 1995 more than one hundred nations endorsed an agreement that
will have profound impacts on biodiversity, climate change and virtually every other major environmental issue. The agreement
is binding and is armed with powerful enforcement measures to ensure that every member lives up to its obligations under the
treaty. The bad news is that this international treaty will be an environmental disaster. Can't guess which agreement this
is? Here are more clues. The treaty wasn't established under the UN Environment Program (UNEP). In fact, it was the product
of highly secretive negotiations conducted by public officials working hand-in-glove with the world's largest corporations.
Nor is it explicitly about the environment. In fact the treaty rarely mentions the word and never even refers to biodiversity,
climate change or desertification. This international 'environment' treaty is, of course, the World Trade Organization's General
Agreement on Trade and Services (GATS). While its proponents deny that it is anything more than a commercial agreement, their
protests betray the dangerously myopic perspective they bring to economic and trade policy. The WTO's environmental relevance
has also been obscured behind a smoke-screen of jargon. In 'tradespeak' environmental standards become 'technical barriers
to trade', food-safety regulations are 'sanitary and phytosanitary measures' while the genetic commons becomes a system of
'intellectual property rights'. This also explains why its backers have been successful in denying the link between trade
agreements and environmental concerns. In broad terms, the WTO is designed to entrench 'grow-now, pay-later' globalization
by removing the power of governments to regulate corporate activity in the public interest. The result is that it will undermine
our capacity to redirect current economic, development and trade policies towards a truly sustainable path. Clear evidence
of its impact can be seen in a number of successful trade challenges to environmental, conservation and food-safety regulations.
Since the WTO was founded four years ago we have watched (its rules prohibit public participation) as the treaty's enforcement
machinery has been wheeled into action to punish governments that flout its rules. The growing list of casualties now includes
European and Japanese food-safety measures, US clean-air regulations and marine mammal conservation laws, aid and development
treaties between Europe and a few impoverished former colonies, and Canadian cultural programs. And the list is likely to
grow. These trade disputes represent only the most visible conflicts between free-trade rules and the environment. Indeed,
the most damaging effects of this new global regime occur out of sight, as governments quietly abandon environmental, conservation,
worker and consumer protections rather than become embroiled in international trade disputes. Lately, many environmentalists
have come to realize that while they were plodding down the hallways of conference centers trying to negotiate international
agreements to combat climate change, protect biodiversity or reduce hazardous-waste trade to poor nations, the ink was drying
on an agreement that would only heap fuel on these ecological fires. This is discouraging, but it is also instructive. The
WTO's authority depends on powerful enforcement machinery and in this regard it offers a model for environmental treaties.
It proves that when governments are motivated they will sign on to truly binding international agreements. Any government
that violates WTO rules is vulnerable to sanctions - often too severe for even the wealthiest nation to ignore. In the organization's
first trade complaint (a challenge by foreign gasoline refiners to US Clean Air Act regulations) the Environmental Protection
Agency was given two options. Either remove the offending statute or face trade sanctions in the order of $150 million a year.
A similar fate befell European food-safety regulations last year when the WTO ruled that a European Community (EC) ban on
hormone-treated beef violated several rules. The Organization ordered the EC to remove its import controls and, when it refused,
authorized trade sanctions worth more than $125 million as the price of its defiance. Moreover, sanctions can be imposed against
unrelated products - wherever they will be felt most. In addition, WTO cases are routinely heard, decided, appealed and resolved
within a year. It would be impossible to find any other legal sanctions against government initiatives that are as quick and
effective as these. In contrast, international environmental agreements rarely use trade sanctions. Even where they do exist
they represent only a pale imitation of the powerful enforcement regime built into the WTO. Agreements like the Framework
Convention on Climate Change and the Biodiversity Convention don't include any enforcement mechanism other than moral persuasion.
This lack of teeth explains why governments have so resolutely ignored commitments they made when they signed these agreements
at the UN's Earth Summit in Rio back in 1992. Ultimately, nation states must face legally binding obligations if international
environmental goals are to be met. This is where we need to tear several pages from the WTO text concerning enforcement. Consider,
for example, the enforcement provisions of the WTO Agreement on Intellectual Property Rights which were written to promote
the interests of global pharmaceutical, biotechnology and media firms. Then imagine environmental goals being taken as seriously
as patent rights. If the WTO were transformed into an organization that was as concerned about climate change as it is about
the growth of transnational drug companies, we could have an Agreement on Trade-Related Measures To Combat Global Warming.
Such an Agreement could require all WTO members to: * adopt domestic laws to stabilize greenhouse-gas emissions at 1990 levels.
* provide for customs inspection, seizure and disposal of goods that were produced in ways that violate the Agreement. * establish
criminal sanctions for any breach of the legislation or regulations mandated by the Agreement. * authorize the use of trade
sanctions, including cross-retaliatory measures - such as prohibiting the export of energy or energy products - against any
jurisdiction that was in breach of its obligations under the Agreement. It is a measure of how much work lies ahead that a
proposal to treat climate change as seriously as pharmaceutical patents would no doubt be greeted with complete incredulity
by the WTO. That's why it's critical that governments be pressed to explain why they consider patent protection a higher priority
than global warming or biodiversity loss. But what then do we do with trade and investment deals that are currently exacerbating
ecological crises? Does the WTO need to be fundamentally overhauled? Or do proposals to delegate environmental issues to a
new UN organization, such as a Global Environmental Organization, make sense? The answer depends on whether you believe that
the environment can be isolated and protected from the main thrust of free-trade policies. In fact, they are cut from the
same cloth. As conflicts between environmental and trade policy became too obvious to deny, free-traders have pushed the environment
debate to the margins within the WTO or isolated it entirely. Current WTO head Michael Moore suggests that environmental issues
don't belong in his agency and should be left to 'specialized institutions' with the expertise to address them. He is hoping
that most people won't appreciate how intimately interrelated trade and environmental issues really are. Of course we do need
to strengthen the mandates of the international environmental institutions. But it is naive to imagine that this can happen
outside the framework of international economic relations. Indeed, the isolation of these organizations from UN agencies like
the World Bank and the WTO explains the marginal influence they have had. The WTO is as much an environmental agreement as
the Basel Convention on Transboundary Waste Shipments is a trade agreement. The distinction is artificial and serves only
to defeat efforts to build a sustainable and integrated model for human development. Trade agreements must serve the goals
of combating climate change, preserving biodiversity, assuring food security and protecting diversity. By the same token,
international environmental agreements must integrate economic and environmental strategies if they are to be effective and
durable. The need for fundamental reform of the WTO is undeniable. But a supranational Global Environment Organization (GEO)
could also play a supportive role by legitimizing the use of trade and economic sanctions. A GEO will have to be equipped
with enforcement mechanisms very much like those of the WTO. Noncompliance would be greeted with sanctions every bit as certain,
swift and substantial as those meted out by the WTO. Economic and trade sanctions might not always be necessary, but they'd
have to be available just in case. It is unlikely that Michael Moore can imagine a GEO to rival the power and influence of
the WTO he now heads. Indeed, the challenge of establishing an effective international environmental regime will be no less
daunting than transforming the WTO. Ultimately, this is because both agendas have precisely the same end point - a treaty
to promote ecological and economic security for all peoples, rather than some grotesque notion of international trade built
on perpetual growth.
p125 [Robin Round directs the Tobin Tax campaign of the Halifax Initiative,
a coalition of Canadian NGOs.] What is the Tobin Tax? In 1978 Nobel Prize-winning economist James Tobin proposed that a small
worldwide tariff (less than half of one per cent) be levied by all major countries on foreign-exchange transactions in order
to 'throw some sand in the wheels' of speculative flows. For a currency transaction to be profitable, the change in value
of the currency must be greater than the proposed tax. Since speculative currency trades occur on much smaller margins, the
Tobin Tax would reduce or eliminate the profits and, logically, the incentive to speculate. The tax is designed to help stabilize
exchange rates by reducing the volume of speculation. And it is set deliberately low so as not to have an adverse effect on
trade in goods and services or long-term investments. How would a Tobin Tax benefit the global economy? It could boost world
trade by helping to stabilize exchange rates. Wildly fluctuating rates play havoc with businesses dependent on foreign exchange
as prices and profits move up and down, depending on the relative value of the currencies being used. When importers and exporters
can't be certain from one day to the next what their money is worth, economic planning - including job creation - goes out
of the window. Reduced exchange-rate volatility means that businesses would need to spend less money 'hedging' (buying currencies
in anticipation of future price changes), thus freeing up capital for investment in new production. Tobin's proposed tax would
not have stopped the crisis in Southeast Asia, but it could help prevent future crises by reducing overall speculative volume
and the volatility that feeds speculative attack. In what way would the Tobin Tax benefit national governments? It is designed
to reduce the power financial markets have to determine the economic policies of national governments. Traditionally, a country's
central bank buys and sells its own currency on international markets to keep its value relatively stable. The bank buys back
its currency when a 'glut' caused by an investor sell-off threatens to reduce the currency's value. In the past, most central
banks had enough cash in reserve to offset any sell-off or 'attack'. Not any longer. Speculators now have more cash than all
the world's central banks put together. Official global reserves are less than half the value of one day of global foreign-exchange
turnover. Many countries are simply unable to protect their currencies from speculative attack. By cutting down on the overall
volume of foreign exchange transactions, a Tobin Tax would mean that central banks would not need as much reserve money to
defend their currency. The tax would allow governments the freedom to act in the best interests of their own economic development,
rather than being forced to shape fiscal and monetary policies according to demands of fickle financial markets. How would
the Tobin Tax benefit people? By making crises less likely, the tax would help avoid the social devastation that occurs in
the wake of a financial crisis. It could also be a significant source of global revenue at a time when foreign aid is decreasing
and strong domestic anti-tax sentiments are reducing the ability of governments to raise revenue. In the face of increasing
income disparity and social inequity, the Tobin Tax represents a rare opportunity to capture the enormous wealth of an untaxed
sector and redirect it towards the public good. Conservative estimates show the tax could yield from $150-300 billion annually.
The UN estimates that the cost of wiping out the worst forms of poverty and environmental destruction globally would be around
$225 billion per year. Who will be taxed ? The majority of foreign-exchange dealing is by 100 of the world's largest banks.
The top ten control 52 per cent of the market and are mostly American, German and British. Citibank tops the list with a 7.75
percent market share and a 1998 volume of foreign exchange transactions which, at $8.5 trillion, exceeded the GDP of the US.
These banks operate in their own interest and on behalf of large corporate and private investors, insurance companies, hedge
funds, mutual funds and pension funds. What will be taxed ? Only specialized financial transactions known as 'spots', 'swaps',
'futures' and 'forwards' will be taxed. With the exception of spot transactions, these instruments are known as 'derivatives'
because their value is derived from the value of an underlying asset which is not bought or sold in the transaction. Tourists
exchanging dollars to pay for their holidays abroad would not be subject to a Tobin Tax. Debate continues as to whether the
tax should apply to any transaction less than a million dollars. How does the Tobin Tax work? The tax would target only speculative
currency transactions. Because it is not easy to determine which types of transactions are speculative and which are associated
with legitimate trade in goods and services, the tax hinges on the speed of a transaction. Speed is the primary difference
between speculative and legitimate trade. Productive investment works on the medium to long term while speculators flip investments
like pancakes, profiting by the daily, hourly and minute-to-minute fluctuations in interest rates and currency values. Eighty
per cent of all speculative transactions occur within seven days or less - 40 per cent occur in two days or less. A Tobin
Tax would automatically penalize short-term exchanges, while barely affecting the incentives for commodity trading and long-term
capital investments. Won't speculators find ways to evade the tax? Inevitably. However, this has never dissuaded governments
from collecting taxes, particularly 'sin taxes' designed to stem unacceptable behavior. The real question is, how do you minimize
evasion? A Tobin Tax could be difficult to evade. Because currency transactions are tracked electronically, in theory the
tax would be easy to collect through the computer systems that record each trade. While the amount of money is enormous, the
number of centers where trading occurs and the number of traders is not. Eighty per cent of foreign-exchange trading takes
place in just seven cities. Agreement by London, New York and Tokyo alone would capture 68 per cent of speculative trading.
Won't speculators still operations to offshore tax havens? Agreement between nations could help avoid the relocation threat,
particularly if the tax were charged at the site where payments are settled or 'netted'. Globally, the move towards a centralized
settlement system means transactions are being tracked by fewer and fewer institutions. Hiding trades is becoming increasingly
difficult. Transfers to tax havens like the Cayman Islands could be penalized at double the agreed rate or more. What is the
biggest barrier to the Tobin Tax? It's not technical or administrative. It's political. The tax is seen as a threat by the
financial community and has met with stiff resistance by a sector with massive political clout. The very idea of putting people
ahead of markets challenges the foundations of the current global economic model and those who control it. Can the opposition
be overcome? In the wake of recent global financial crises governments everywhere are examining their faith in free markets.
Even the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund praised Malaysia's use of capital controls to jump-start its battered
economy in 1997-8. This is a fundamental shift in attitude, unimaginable until recently. The political appeal of this tax
to cash-strapped governments and multilateral agencies worldwide can't be underestimated. At the UN Social Summit +5 in Geneva
in June 2000, 160 governments agreed to conduct a rigorous analysis on new and innovative sources of funding for social development,
including a currency transaction tax. NGOs from around the world fought hard for this crucial study and believe it will make
a significant contribution to the intergovernmental debate on a Tobin Tax. Who supports the Tobin Tax? The international trade
union movement, the Canadian Parliament, the Finnish Government and a growing number of academics and elected representatives
all support the tax. The European Parliament, and parliamentarians in the UK and France have held debates on the Tobin proposal
and groups of parliamentarians are active in Brazil and throughout Europe. Over 400 parliamentarians from 21 countries have
signed a World Parliamentarians Call for a Tobin Tax and 160 economists from 29 countries signed a similar appeal launched
in June 2000. Citizens' movements for a Tobin Tax are active around the world. These include: CIDSE in Europe, the Halifax
Initiative in Canada, KEPA in Finland, War on Want in Britain, ATTAC in France and Brazil, CCEJ in Korea and the Tobin Tax
Initiative in the US. These and other groups have established the International Tobin Tax Network to share information and
coordinate actions as they work to build public and political support for the tax. This is only one aspect of the fundamental
reform of the global financial system and is not a panacea for the world's financial ills and development woes. The democratization
of economic decision-making and the equitable redistribution of wealth must become the central principles upon which governments
act in the new millennium. The real work has just begun. Citizens and politicians around the world must not let the powerful
forces who oppose the Tobin Tax stifle, manipulate and ultimately undermine an essential public debate on controlling global
financial markets. The Tobin Tax deserves a fair hearing. Only widespread popular support and public pressure can ensure it.
p133 [Tony Clarke is Director of the Polaris Institute in Ottawa,
Canada and board member of the International Forum on Globalization.] As a rich-nations club where most of the 'Global Fortune
500' - the biggest and wealthiest corporations - are based, the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD)
is not the place to construct an alternative treaty along these lines. Nor is the World Trade Organization (WTO). Although
the WTO includes most of the world's nation states, its power structure is heavily weighted against the developing countries.
The only appropriate place is the UN itself. Despite disturbing signs of corporate infiltration in UN affairs, the foundation
for developing an alternative framework is located there, along with more equitable decision-making. What is required is leadership
within UN circles to kick-start the process. The main principles of an Alternative Investment Treaty should include: * Citizens'
rights- Investment should be designed to ensure that capital serves the basic rights and needs of all citizens including:
human rights (adequate food, clothing, shelter); social rights (quality health care, education, social services); labor rights
(employment, fair wages, unions, health and safety standards); environmental rights (protection of air, waters, forests, fish,
wildlife and nonrenewable resources) and cultural rights (preservation of peoples' identity, values, customs, heritage). *
State responsibilities - To ensure that citizens' rights are respected governments have the right and responsibility to regulate
the national economy. These powers should include the right to protect strategic areas of their economies (finance, energy,
communications) by establishing public enterprises. And the right to protect sensitive areas known as the 'commons' (the environment,
health care, culture) through government-run public services. * Corporate obligations - Although foreign-based corporations
can expect fair treatment and a reasonable return on investment (compensation for expropriation of assets) they must maintain
certain social obligations such as performance standards designed to ensure citizens' basic needs and rights. They must also
recognize that governments have the right to protect and enhance strategic areas of their economies and the 'commons'. And
they must contribute a portion of their capital to the 'commons' by paying their fair share of taxes. An Alternative Investment
Treaty based on these fundamental principles would include the following key elements: * Fair treatment - Foreign investment
would be welcome provided social obligations were met. The concept of 'national treatment', which is used to force governments
to treat foreign corporations on the same terms as domestic companies, should be discarded. Instead the 'stored value' of
capital would be the basis for establishing obligations for fair treatment of foreign-based corporations. * Social obligations
- Governments would have the legal right to require all corporations, both foreign and domestic, to meet basic social obligations
such as labor standards, environmental safeguards and social-security contributions. * Performance standards - To ensure that
foreign investment serves national-development priorities, governments would be allowed to require standards such as job quotas,
balancing imports with exports, quotas on natural-resource exports or restrictions on the repatriation of profits. In return
for access to a country's markets and resources, a government could require that a foreign company create a specified number
of new jobs in the community or adhere to restrictions on the export of nonrenewable resources. These initiatives are both
feasible and practical. Canada's Foreign Investment Review Act once provided the Canadian Government with the policy tools
to apply this kind of performance requirement on foreign investments. * Investment incentives - To ensure that corporations
keep these social obligations, governments may use investment 'incentives' including: grants, loans and subsidies; procurement
practices; tax incentives and limits on profit remittances for foreign companies that fail their social obligations. Governments
could decide, for example, to buy from either foreign or domestic companies as a way of attracting productive investment.
* Public enterprises - All governments have a responsibility to use tax revenues for protecting the 'commons' through public
investments. These could include exercising public ownership over key sectors of the economy; establishing social programs
and public services; safeguarding ecologically sensitive areas; and protecting cultural heritage. * Expropriation measures
- Fair compensation should be paid to foreign corporations whose physical assets are expropriated for public purposes. But
not when social or environmental regulations add to business costs. Compensation should be determined by national law with
due regard to the value of the initial investment, the valuation of the properties for tax purposes and the amount of wealth
taken out of the country during the period of investment. So a foreign corporation could not demand compensation for an environmental
law that placed a quota on the export of a nonrenewable resource or a health ban on the sale of toxic substances, on the grounds
that such measures would reduce the corporation's profit margins. Nor could a foreign company claim compensation for loss
of future profits because government actions prevent a planned investment from going ahead. * Financial transactions - All
governments have a right to require that foreign investment be used for productive rather than speculative purposes; that
foreign corporations deposit a percentage of their profits in the central bank for a specified minimum period; that foreign-exchange
transactions be taxed in order to slow down currency speculation. For example, to prevent the sudden exodus of speculative
capital from Chile, 'speed bump' measures were introduced which required investment to remain in the country for at least
a year. * Dispute settlement- In the event of a dispute citizens, governments and corporations would all have the right to
be heard. Disputes filed by citizens would be heard by national courts which would have powers to invoke injunctions and award
monetary compensation. Through this process any one of the three parties with legal standing could bring a suit for monetary
compensation but not for violation of the investment rules aimed at striking down national laws. To ensure that non-governmental
organizations (NGOs), native communities, environment and women's groups, trade unions and others have equal access to the
dispute-settlement mechanism, national and international funds should be established for citizen intervenors.
|